The production function simply states the quantity of output (q) that a firm can produce as a function of the quantity of inputs to production, or . There can be a number of different inputs to production, i.e. "factors of production," but they are generally designated as either capital or labor. (Technically, land is a third category of factors of production, but it's not generally included in the production function except in the context of a land-intensive business.) The particular functional form of the production function (i.e. the specific definition of f) depends on the specific technology and production processes that a firm uses.
In the short run,
the amount of capital that a factory uses is generally thought to be fixed. (The
reasoning is that firms must commit to a particular size of factory, office,
etc. and can't easily change these decisions without a long planning period.)
Therefore, the quantity of labor (L) is the only input in the short-run
production function. In the long run,
on the other hand, a firm has the planning horizon necessary to change not only
the number of workers but the amount of capital as well, since it can move to a
different size factory, office, etc. Therefore, the long-run production
function has two inputs that be changed- capital (K) and labor (L). Both cases
are shown in the diagram above.
Note that the quantity of
labor can take on a number of different units- worker-hours, worker-days, etc.
The amount of capital is somewhat ambiguous in terms of units, since not all
capital is equivalent, and no one wants to count a hammer the same as a
forklift, for example. Therefore, the units that are appropriate for the
quantity of capital will depend on the specific business and production
function.
The Production Function in the Short Run
Because there is only one
input (labor) to the short-run production function, it's pretty straightforward
to depict the short-run production function graphically. As shown in the above
diagram, the short-run production function puts the quantity of labor (L) on
the horizontal axis (since it's the independent variable) and the quantity of
output (q) on the vertical axis (since it's the dependent variable).
The
short-run production function has two notable features. First, the curve starts
at the origin, which represents the observation that the quantity of output
pretty much has to be zero if the firm hires zero workers. (With zero workers,
there isn't even a guy to flip a switch to turn on the machines!) Second, the
production function gets flatter as the amount of labor increases, resulting in
a shape that is curved downward. Short-run production functions typically
exhibit a shape like this due to the phenomenon of
In general, the short-run
production function slopes upwards, but it is possible for it to slope
downwards if adding a worker causes him to get in everyone else's way enough
such that output decreases as a result.
The
Production Function in the Long Run
You can think of this graph
as a topographical map of quantity, with each line on the graph representing a
particular quantity of output. (This may seem like a familiar concept if you
have already studied indifference
curves!) In fact, each line on this graph is called an
"isoquant" curve, so even the term itself has its roots in
"same" and "quantity."
Why is each output quantity
represented by a line and not just by a point? In the long run, there are often
a number of different ways to get a particular quantity of output. If one were
making sweaters, for example, one could choose to either hire a bunch of
knitting grandmas or rent some mechanized knitting looms. Both approaches would
make sweaters perfectly fine, but the first approach entails a lot of labor and
not much capital (i.e. is labor intensive), while the second requires a lot of
capital but not much labor (i.e. is capital intensive). On the graph, the labor
heavy processes are represented by the points toward the bottom right of the
curves, and the capital heavy processes are represented by the points toward
the upper left of the curves. In general, curves that are further away from the
origin correspond to larger quantities of output. (In the diagram above, this
implies that q3 is greater than q2, which is greater than
q1.) This is simply because curves that are further away from the
origin are using more of both capital and labor in each production
configuration. It is typical (but not necessary) for the curves to be shaped
like the ones above, as this shape reflects the tradeoffs between capital and
labor that are present in many production processes.