Search

23 September, 2021

Perfect Competition, Monopoly, Imperfect Competition , Monopolistic Competition, Oligopoly

 Perfect Competition

 Perfect competition assumes that consumers are rational utility maximizers, know their own tastes and preferences, and have perfect information on prices and other characteristics of goods and services; and that firms are rational profit maximizers, produce homogeneous, identical goods within each industry, face no restriction moving into or out of an industry, and have perfect information on the opportunity cost of all resources. Both consumers and firms are price takers; there are such a large number of both that their individual actions have a negligible effect on the price and quantity exchanged in the market.

 Each individual firm under perfect competition faces a perfectly elastic demand curve: Each firm can sell all the output it can produce at the going price, but it cannot sell any output at higher than the going price and has no incentive to sell any output at lower than the going price. This means AR=MR=Price. The firm cannot control price, so it controls quantity and chooses to produce the quantity that maximizes profit, which is the quantity where MC=MR (=AR=Price). If, at this quantity, the price is higher than the average total cost, then excess profit exists and resources will move into the industry, shifting the supply curve to the right and reducing price and profits. Resources will continue to move into the industry until ATC=MC (=MR=AR=Price). If below normal profit exists, then resources will move out of the industry, shifting the supply curve to the left and increasing price and profits. Resources will continue to move out of the industry until ATC=MC.

 Economic efficiency requires that the ratio MU/MC be equal for all goods. Under perfect competition, utility maximizing consumer behavior will ensure that MU/P is equal for all goods, and the behavior of profit maximizing firms will ensure that P=MC for all goods. Therefore, MU/MC will be equal for all goods, and economic efficiency will be achieved.

 Monopoly

 A monopolist is a producer who supplies the complete market for a good or service. Barriers to entry prevent new firms from entering the market. Barriers to entry could be patents, legal protections, or financial disincentives such as economies of scale.

 Since a monopolist is the sole provider, the firm’s marginal cost curve (which is the firm’s supply curve) becomes the industry supply curve. There is also no difference between the market and individual demand curves for a monopolist, since there is only one firm.

 The monopolist faces a downward sloping demand curve, which is the same as its average revenue curve. When average revenue is decreasing, marginal revenue must by definition be less than average revenue. The monopolist follows the same profit maximization rule as anyone else: Produce until MR=MC. But since AR (the demand curve) is greater than MC at this quantity, the monopolist earns above normal profits. This is a short run equilibrium position. However, there are no new firms to enter the profit and drive down the above normal profit in the long run. The only change in the long run is that the monopolist will adjust plant size so that LRMC=MR. But the monopolist will only act to increase profit, so the above normal profit is the same or higher in the long run.

 Economic efficiency, which requires that the ratio of MU/MC be equal for all goods, will not exist when monopoly conditions exist. The ratio of MU/P will still be equal for all goods because of utility maximizing consumer behavior. However, the monopolist sets P=AR and MR=MC where AR>MR, hence P>MC. The ratio MU/MC for the monopolistic good will be higher than for other goods.

 Despite this economic inefficiency, it may be in society’s best interest to have only one producer of a good or service when economies of scale exist. Economies of scale exist where average costs decline as plant size and output increases. Under these conditions, one firm can produce a given output for less cost than would be incurred if many small firms attempted to produce the same total output. Under these conditions, in the absence of government intervention, there will be a tendency for monopoly to arise. The largest firm in the industry has a cost advantage over all smaller firms and can charge a lower price that drives all competitors out of the market. The alternative is for firms to get together and act like a monopoly, splitting the profits between them—an illegal activity in many countries.

 Many competitive firms, each operating a small plant at a high average cost, may cost society more resources to produce the same output as a monopolist, even including the monopolist’s above normal profit.

 Imperfect Competition / Monopolistic Competition

 An imperfectly competitive industry consists of large numbers of firms each facing a downward sloping demand curve for its goods or services. Firms have a degree of control over price, possibly because there are real or imagined differences between their products and those of competitors, due to elements of local monopoly like the corner grocery store being more convenient to consumers who live nearby, or perhaps for other reasons. The more these factors exist, the more inelastic the firm’s demand curve will be. In the case of a corner store, if they increase prices they will certainly lose some business, but some people will continue to pay the higher price because of the time and inconvenience involved in going “into town.”

 Since each firm faces a downward sloping demand curve, average revenue and marginal revenue will diverge, as they do under a monopoly, but by much less. Again as with a monopoly, firms will expand or contract output so that MC=MR. But since the demand curve (AR) is greater than MR, above normal profits will be earned. This will provide an incentive for new firms to move into the industry. Assuming factor prices remain constant, the demand curve of existing firms will shift to the left until, in long run equilibrium, the firm’s demand curve is tangential to its average cost curve (AR < ATC for all points except one where AR=ATC, which also happens to be the quantity where MR=MC). Normal profit is thus earned.

 However, the point where AR=ATC is not the point of minimum ATC. A monopolistic competitor in long-term equilibrium produces at a quantity where ATC is higher than minimum, or in other words where spare capacity exists. At the same time, price is higher than MC, so economic inefficiency results. If the firm were to produce at minimum ATC, at which point price would equal MC since MC intersects ATC at the minimum point, ATC would be higher than AR and the firm would incur a loss. There is therefore no incentive for firms to produce beyond the point where AR=ATC (and MR=MC).

 The implication of imperfect competition is that spare capacity exists and this produces economic inefficiency, even though above normal profits are not being earned. This inefficiency must be set against the product differentiation which such firms provide society.

 Oligopoly

 An oligopoly is an industry where a small number of firms produce the bulk of the industry’s output. Each firm competes with the others in an interdependent manner; every firm’s sales depends not only on the price it charges, but also on the prices charged by its competitors. Because there are few firms and because there are real or imagined differences between them, the demand curve faced by each firm is downward sloping. However, many of the goods and services produced by oligopolists are essentially homogeneous. Barriers to entry in oligopolies are largely the same as for monopolies: Economies of scale, patents, or the sheer size and complexity of the firms involved.

 Unlike perfect competition, when an oligopolist changes their price, the other producers are likely to react. If one firm raises its price, most of its customers will switch to other firms (assuming they do not raise prices to match). So above the going price, the demand curve is highly elastic. If one firm lowers its price, the other firms will lower theirs to match, so the quantity sold will not change much. So below the going price, the demand curve is relatively inelastic. This results in a “kinked” demand curve. Since the demand curve (=average revenue curve) is downward sloping, the marginal revenue curve is also downward sloping and below the demand curve. At the point where the kink appears in the demand curve, the marginal revenue curve is vertical over some price range. As a result, there is a range of marginal costs over which the profit maximizing price is the same.

 The long term profit maximizing strategy for an oligopolist is not simple because it depends on what the competitors will do. This is what has led to the compexity of airline pricing. The easiest solution is for the oligopolists to to form a cartel, establish the industry-wide profit maximizing price, and earn monopoly profits. Fortunately this is illegal. What oligopolists can do legally is to implicitly elect one firm as the “price leader” and have all other firms match any price changes. This is legal so long as the firms act only on publically available data and do not collude.