Several steps are essential for successful execution of advertising campaigns in financial services.
Search
24 September, 2021
Explain the different steps in advertising for bank or financial services institutions
23 September, 2021
National Macroeconomic Goals
In considering macroeconomic ‘good’ and ‘bad,’ consumption and investment expenditure are clearly in the ‘good’ column. Equally clearly, unemployment and inflation are in the ‘bad’ column. But other ‘goods’ and ‘bads’ exist which are less clear. Some amount of government expentiture is clearly good; government must at a minimum establish the rule of law, and deal with market failures such as public goods and externalities. However, a large spending defecit is generally considered a ‘bad.’ International trade is also generally a ‘good’ because it permits higher living standards than would be possible in a closed economy. However, it is not clear what the ideal balanace of trade would be. Would you prefer X>Z, a sign of strength like Japan or Germany, or Z>X, a higher use of foreign resources? Or would you prefer to maintain X=Z, resulting in a stable currency on foreign exchange markets?
The Keynesian Theory of Money
Where the quantity theory treats money exclusively as a medium of exchange, they Keynesian theory stresses that money serves other functions as well. There are three types of demand for money balances:
·
The transactions demand,
which arises from the fact that people need money to finance current
transactions. Households and firms hold money balances to bridge the gap
between the reciept of income and its expenditure. The amount of money held for
such purposes will be closely related to the level of national income. However,
it is also likely to be influenced by the rate of interest. If the rate of
interest is high, there will be a strong motive to avoid holding money and
instead hold interest bearing assets.
·
The precautionary demand, which consists of money to be held
to meet the sudden arrival of unforseen circumstances. Again, the main factor
likely to influence this amount is the level of income, though again high
interest rates will tend to push money out of this category.
·
The speculative demand, which emphasizes the use of money
as a store of wealth rather than a medium of exchange. Holding money has an
opportunity cost: The income or utility foregone on the investments or goods
the money could have bought. Therefore it would seem that households and firms
ought immediately to invest or spend all money above that required for transactional
and precautionary needs. However, in the presence of uncertainty, individuals
or firms will sometimes believe that the returns available in the future might
be sufficiently better than the returns available today that it is worth
waiting.
The point on
the demand curve that intersects with the (vertical) money supply curve will
determine the equilibrium rate of interest. MT+P represents the
amount of money held for transactional and precautionary purposes, which for
our purposes is assumed to vary only with Y. Since Y is held constant here, MT+P
is a vertical line: At all rates of interest, the same amount of money is held.
The speculative demand for money is a function of the rate of interest,
reflected in the sloped portion of the demand curve. However, once a
sufficiently low interest rate is reached, the curve becomes horizontal. This
reflects the observation that at very low interest rates, households and firms
are simply not interested in buying any more bonds. For one thing, the interest
rate is so low that everyone is convinced it should rise soon, so nobody will
want to invest in current, low-yield bonds. Once this point has been reached,
further increases in the money supply will simply find their way to idle
balances and further reductions in the interest rate will not occur.
Money
The models so far have not included the concept of money. This is unsatisfactory because money clearly plays a part in economics. A complete macroeconomics theory must be capable of explaining the historical behavior of the price level. In addition, money may have an importance beyond the simple measure of prices, because monetary factors may influence “real” values such as output, income and employment.
·
Coins
·
Notes
·
Bank
deposits
·
A
medium of exchange: Without money, goods and services could only be traded
through bartering, which is wasteful and difficult, particularly in a highly
specialized modern economy. Money is used as a universally acceptable barter
substitute. To be useful for this purpose, money must posess the following
characteristics:
-
it
must be widely acceptable;
-
it
must have a high value to weight ratio;
-
it
must be divisible to settle debts of differing values;
-
it
must be difficult to reproduce, counterfeit or debase in value.
·
A
unit of account or measure of value: Money provides a standard by which the
value of any good or service can be measured. If a car costs $25,000 and a
hamburger costs $2, then a car is worth, and can be exchanged for, 12,500
hamburgers.
·
A
store of wealth: A household (or firm) can sell its factor services or goods
for money, and then keep the money until it has decided what to do with it.
Almost every household and firm holds some amount of money. To act as a
satisfactory store of wealth, the value of money must be reasonably stable over
time.
Circular Flow of Income
In order to develop a simple short-run model of the economy, we make the following assumptions:
·
That
technical knowledge and resources are fixed in the short run
·
That
there is a fixed relationship between output and employment
·
There
is no international trade
·
There
is no government sector; ie there are no taxes and no government expenditure
·
Firms
distribute all profit to their owners (households) immediately when it is
earned
·
All
investment is carried out by firms
·
All
prices are constant, so that any change in numeric GNP is caused by a change in
real GNP.
·
By
finding the total expenditure on final goods and services
·
By
finding the value added by each producer
·
By
finding the total income earned by each factor of production
·
Wages
and salaries – paid in exchange for the use of labor services
·
Rent
– paid in return for the use of land and capital goods not owned by the
producer
·
Interest
– paid to the households who have loaned money to purchase land and capital
·
Gross
profits – residual money accruing to the firm after payment has been made to
all other factors, usually distributed in the form of dividends to the
households that own the firm
The result
of Y=$50 billion is a result of the savings plans of households. If firms
output Y by a lesser amount, say to Y=$70 billion, then households will plan to
save $14 billion, which is still higher than the investment plans of firms. A
new equilibrium will not be reached until the savings plans of households again
equal the investment plans of firms. There is a multiplier effect in evidence
here: A change of $10 billion in the savings plans of households has caused a
change of $50 billion in GNP.
Output and Inflation, Inflationary Bias, Properties of the Phillips Curve
Output and Inflation
In the real world, the constraint that Y cannot exceed Q is somewhat relaxed, because of the way we have defined full employment. Facing demand exceeding Q, some fatories and workers can work overtime and the average frictional and structural rates of unemployment will fall because there are so many unfilled vacancies. Thus the economy in the short run can ‘squeeze’ some extra production out of its resources. However, the cost of this economic ‘boom’ is that factor prices will rise and consequently the price level will rise at a rate higher than normal. This is represented by the increasing slope of the Phillips Curve as unemployment goes above UF.
Employment vs. Inflation in the Long
Run
Demand Deficient Unemployment
Once all the factors causing ‘full employment unemployment’ are taken into account, any additional unemployment left over must be the result of too little aggregate demand. This is called demand deficient unemployment. Demand deficient unemployment occurs when the number of people unemployed (U) is greater than the number of unfilled job vacancies (V). If accurate values could be determined for U and V, full employment could be defined as occuring when V >= U. Unfortunately, even though reasonably good unemployment data exists, the number of job vacancies is difficult to determine—many job vacancies are never advertised, and sometimes managers may even disagree over whether a particular vacancy exists or not! For this reason, full employment is usually taken to be some set target rate of unemployment. The full employment rate of employment varies over time for any one country and varies substantially between countries.
In other words, for each 3%
that actual output falls short of potential output, the unemployment rate will
exceed the full employment rate by 1%. So if Y is 12% below Q, U will be 4%
above UF. Looking at it another way, Okun’s Law states that for
every 1% additional unemployment, 3% of potential output is lost and gone
forever.
Factors Determining Unemployment
The most important factors determining the level of frictional, structural and seasonal unemployment are:
Level of Economic Activity – When
actual output is close to potential output, employers will face a competitive
labor market. Employers will be more likely to advertise and to spend on
recruiting. Employers will also likely offer better retraining programs and
relocation assistance. These measures will reduce structural unemployment. When
unemployment is high, companies will have an easier time finding employees to
hire and will be less willing to pay for this type of program.
Transmission of Information – Jobs
cannot be filled unless job-seekers can find out about openings and hiring
managers can find out about candidates. The more effectively the information is
transferred, the lower frictional (and to some extent structural) unemployment
will be.
Structural Change – The overall
composition of the goods produced by an economy changes with time, as tastes
change, new products are invented, world trade patterns move production of
particular goods between different nations, etc. Sometimes it changes quickly,
sometimes slowly. If structural change is occuring at a rapid pace, the number
of people unemployed due to having the wrong skills or living in the wrong
location will tend to be higher.
Workforce Mobility – The easier it is
to change location, and the easier it is to gain training in new fields, the
lower structural unemployment will be. This will depend on factors such as the
cost and availability of training, the cost of travel and moving expenses, the
degree to which appropriate schools and hospitals are universally available,
and so forth.
Institutional Restrictions and
Barriers – Governments, trade unions and even employers will sometimes take
actions designed to protect particular groups of workers. These actions reduce
the efficiency of the labor market and lead to additional structural and
frictional unemployment. Examples: restrictive union practices, required
professional certifications, pension and medical plans tied to the job, or even
local policies which favor existing residents over new arrivals.
Seasonal Industries – Some industries
are seasonal by nature: Fishing, farming, forestry, tourism, construction.
Despite the fact that predictable unemployment will occur in some periods of
the yearly cycle, some economies have clear natural advantages in these
industries and find it worthwhile to pursue them.
Potential Output in the Short Run, Potential Output in the Long Run
If we could take a snapshot of the economy at a specific point in time, it would be possible to enumerate all available resources, both capital and labor, and calculate the maximum possible output if all resources were put to their most productive use. This is the potential output of the economy.
This graph can be shown to illustrate the microeconomic question of what to produce. At the point X on the graph, the production of B2-B1 additional butter requires the sacrifice (opportunity cost) of the production of G1-G2 additional guns. The opportunity cost is determined by the slope of the production possibility frontier. When society is operating at some point within but not on the frontier, it is possible to produce additional units of one or both goods with no sacrifice to production of the other good; ie, no opportunity cost. An economically rational society will therefore always desire to operate on the frontier.
The
situation when attempting to decide if more of one good should be produced is
different depending on whether society is on the production possibilities
frontier. If the economy is currently operating below the frontier, then any
decision to produce more of one good can be taken in the absence of information
about other goods. However, if the economy is at the frontier, the decision
must also include the opportinity cost of output foregone in the other good.
The first major macroeconomic question is therefore whether or not the economy
is operating on the frontier.
Aggregate Demand
GNP is purchased by four groups. The sume of the expenditure of the four groups is known as aggregate demand. The four groups are:
·
Consumers
(households)
·
Firms
·
Government
·
International
(foreign households, firms and governments)
-
Y
= aggregate demand, aka GNP, GNI, GNE
-
C
= consumption expenditure
-
I
= investment expenditure
-
X
= production of export goods
-
Z
= expenditure on import goods
Balance of Payments
A nation’s balance of payments is a complex set of accounts. There are three major accounts involved:
·
Capital
Account: Records all trades which affect the amount of claims the nation has
abroad, both for and against. Or in other words, all borrowing and lending
activity.
·
Official
Settlements Account: Records the changes in currency reserves held in all
foreign currencies.
Foreign Exchange
When an individual in one country wants to buy products from another, they must first buy some of the currency of the other country. The exchange rate between country A and country B (in a two-country model) is the same as a price in any competitive market. The demand curve for A’s currency is determined by the people who want to buy products produced by A, and the supply curve is determined by the people from A who want to buy products produced in B. As the exchange rate fluctuates, goods produced in country A will seem more or less expensive to residents of country B and vice versa, altering the quantity demanded and supplied. This is called a flexible exchange rate.
Support for Trade Restrictions
There are some economically valid arguments in favor of trade restrictions. The major ones are:
-
Dumping:
Dumping is the practice of selling goods in a foreign market at a price lower
than that which prevails in the domestic market. The intent is (presumed to be)
to drive domestic producers out of business, after which a price hike can be
expected.
-
Countervailing
Duties: If goods are produced in a nation where the industry is subsidized, and
then sold in a nation where no such subsidy exists, then domestic producers
will be at a competitive disadvantage to imports from the subsidizing nation.
Where such an imbalance exists, it is acceptable to impose a tariff intended to
just equal the advantage provided by the subsidization.
-
Squeaky
Wheels: While on average everyone benefits from free trade, individually some
people lose badly—because they are laid off, or their business cannot compete,
or what have you. It is difficult to build a political organization a large
number of small gainers, but it is relatively easy to build a political
organization around a small number of big losers; say, unemployed steel workers
in Pennsylvania. While theoretically it is possible for the losers to be
compensated from the benefits of the gainers, in practice this rarely (if ever)
happens.